1. Context & Introduction
Smallholder farmers dominate Pakistani agriculture – about 64% of farms are under 5 acres (2 hectares) (Ali, 2023). With such small landholdings, most cannot afford to own costly machines outright. Yet during peak seasons – like the rabi (winter) wheat sowing in November or the kharif (summer) rice harvest in September – the urgency for machinery is immense. Crops must be planted and harvested within narrow windows to avoid yield losses from late sowing or weather damage. For example, wheat fields need quick harvesting before spring rains, and rice nurseries must be transplanted on time; delays can cut yields significantly. This makes access to tractors, combine harvesters, threshers, laser land levelers, and transport absolutely critical for small farmers' livelihoods.
Pakistan's overall farm mechanization remains low (an estimated 35% mechanization rate vs ~70% in Europe) (Business Recorder, 2025), but it is growing through these informal rental markets. In provinces like Punjab – the country's breadbasket – most wheat cultivation steps are now mechanized, from land preparation to seeding and harvesting (FAO, 2024). Smallholders who cannot buy equipment hire it from others on a short-term basis, enabling them to benefit from modern technology without the upfront cost. "Providing these machines on a rental basis to farmers can ensure higher crop yields and better-quality produce," notes Dr. Khan of the University of Agriculture Faisalabad (Saleem, 2025). Indeed, farmers consistently report that timely access to tractors or harvesters is a "game-changer" for productivity (Saleem, 2025). The informal rental network – a patchwork of local service providers – has become the backbone of smallholder mechanization in regions like Punjab and Sindh.

Farmers thresh wheat with a tractor-powered machine in rural Punjab. Rentals like this help smallholders complete harvests on time.Photo credit: Hamza Awan
2. Types of Rental Service Providers
Several types of local entrepreneurs provide machinery services to small farmers, often in informal arrangements. They include large farmers who own surplus equipment, dedicated rental entrepreneurs, mechanics with equipment, and even returning migrants investing in rural businesses. Below we profile these provider types, including how they acquire machinery and operate:
- Large Landowners with Surplus Machinery: In many villages, a big landlord or “zamindar” owns more tractors or implements than he needs for his own acreage. During off-peak times on his farm, he hires out this equipment (with an operator) to neighboring small farmers. For example, Muhammad Raza (pseudonym), who farms 50 acres in central Punjab, owns two Massey Ferguson tractors (50 HP and 85 HP models). After finishing his land preparation, Raza’s drivers plow fields for smallholders in the village at a rate of around PKR 3,000 per acre (about $10.7). Raza’s family purchased their tractors outright using profits from high-yield harvests and partial government subsidies. Like him, many medium-to-large farmers extend tractor hire services to utilize their machines fully – studies show medium farmers in Pakistan and India log ~700 hours per year hiring out their tractors, over half of total usage (Houssou, Asante-Addo, Diao, & Kolavalli, 2015). These owners typically finance machinery from farm income or subsidized credit schemes, and renting to neighbors provides a side income that helps cover fuel and maintenance. As “insiders” in the community, large farmers-turned-service-providers often have an established client base and trust; farmers know them personally and may even repay service fees after harvest (a common practice of informal credit). Most tractor service providers are indeed farmers themselves with landholdings roughly twice that of their client farmers (Houssou, Asante-Addo, Diao, & Kolavalli, 2015), reflecting how bigger landowners support smaller ones.
- Entrepreneurs Investing in Machinery Rental: Some individuals go into the machinery-hire business as a standalone enterprise. These are people who might not farm much land themselves but see opportunity in owning equipment to rent out across multiple villages. Often they are enterprising rural youth or local businesspeople. They may start with one tractor or a combine harvester, building a network by moving their machine from farm to farm during peak demand. For instance, Ali Shah, an entrepreneur in Sindh, purchased a used combine harvester (a Chinese-made model) specifically to provide custom harvesting services for wheat and rice growers. He obtained an equipment loan of PKR 2 million (≈$7,140) through a bank leasing program to finance the purchase, and he hires two operators. During April’s wheat harvest in Punjab and Sindh, Ali’s combine works non-stop on client fields, charging about PKR 5,000 per acre (≈$18) for harvesting and bagging grain. In the off-season, he transports the machine to the next region where a crop is ripening – a model similar to custom harvesters in India. These dedicated rental entrepreneurs often rely on bank credit or informal loans to buy equipment, expecting to pay it off through service fees over several seasons. Their business model is volume-driven: serving many small farms sequentially. Branding and trust matter; some even name their service (e.g. “Sindh Agri Services”) and guarantee timely work to compete with ad-hoc providers. However, building a clientele from scratch is challenging – newcomers must convince farmers to trust an outsider, and they often start by offering slightly lower rates or more flexible payment terms until they establish a reputation.
- Local Mechanics who Rent Out Equipment: Village workshop owners and mechanics are another key group. Because they have technical know-how, they sometimes acquire tractors or implements, maintain them, and rent them out to farmers. A mechanic might start by buying a second-hand Fiat/New Holland 60 HP tractor (locally called “Ghazi”) that he repaired, then use it both as a demo of his mechanical skills and as a rental unit. For example, Umar, a tractor mechanic in southern Punjab, saved money from his repair business and bought a used tractor for PKR 1.5 million (≈$5,360). He not only fixes other farmers’ machines but also hires his tractor for jobs like rotavator tilling, laser land leveling, and hauling crops. Because Umar can service the tractor himself, his operating costs are lower and he can charge affordable rates. Mechanics-turned-providers often finance equipment through personal savings or by pooling money with relatives. Their advantage is technical skill – they keep machines in good condition and can minimize breakdowns during a rental job. Farmers also like that a knowledgeable mechanic is operating or overseeing the work, as it gives confidence in machine quality. These providers may bundle services: for instance, offering a tractor + thresher hire along with on-call repair service. On the downside, being a one-man operation can limit how many clients they serve at peak time. Nonetheless, many rural mechanics have become important “go-to” service providers for smallholders needing reliable equipment on rent.
- Returning Migrants Investing in Machinery: Remittances from overseas workers often fuel rural investments. It’s not uncommon for a family with a member working abroad (in the Gulf, for example) to invest the saved capital in farm machinery back home. Such returning migrants or their families purchase tractors, threshers or transport trucks as a business venture, providing rental services locally. Consider Yasir, who worked in Saudi Arabia for years and amassed savings. Upon returning to his hometown in Sindh, he bought a brand-new Massey Ferguson 75 HP tractor (costing around PKR 3.7 million, ≈$13,200 for a 2WD model (Tractors.com.pk, 2025)) and a set of implements. Since Yasir’s own landholding is small (just 5 acres), he rents out the tractor to other farmers almost full-time – effectively acting as a custom hiring service. His brothers manage the bookings while Yasir occasionally drives the tractor or supervises. Migrant investors often finance machines entirely from their overseas earnings (avoiding loans), which gives them an asset-based income on return. They tend to bring a somewhat business-oriented approach: keeping logs of hours worked and cultivating a broad client network beyond just their village. Many also introduce popular international brands they saw abroad – for example, some have imported a used Kubota combine or a John Deere tractor to start a rental service, though the dominant machines remain local makes (Massey Ferguson by Millat Tractors and New Holland Fiat by Al-Ghazi in Pakistan). This trend of diaspora-funded machinery has injected fresh capital and newer equipment into the informal rental market.
Each provider type contributes to a patchwork of rental services accessible to smallholders. In Punjab alone, over 20,000 private service providers are registered for renting and operating farm machinery (FAO, 2024) – and many more operate informally. They obtain machines through various financing routes (from subsidies and bank leases to personal savings) and run different business models, but collectively they ensure that even a 2-acre farmer can hire a 50 HP tractor or a combine harvester on demand. Most machinery in use is in the medium horsepower range (30–75 HP), which suits small farms (FAO, 2024). Common tractor models are the Massey Ferguson 240 (50HP) and Fiat 480 “Ghazi” (55HP) for plowing and transport, while combines include re-conditioned imports (often old Class/New Holland combines) and increasingly smaller Asian harvesters like Kubota for rice (FAO, 2024). The presence of these providers has effectively created an informal farm mechanization network owned and operated by rural entrepreneurs themselves, rather than large companies. Brief personal profiles (like those above) show the diversity of actors – from landlord to mechanic – all playing a part in this service economy.
3. Pricing and Market Structures
How are rental prices set? In Pakistan’s informal machinery rental market, pricing is typically negotiated per job, with several common charging methods: per acre, per hour, or per unit of output/service. The method often depends on the task and local norms:
- Land preparation (ploughing, tilling): Usually charged per acre for plowing or rotavating a field. In some regions it may be quoted per hour of tractor work if soil conditions vary. For example, a tractor owner might ask for PKR 2,500–3,500 per acre (≈$9–$12) to plough, which roughly factors in fuel and labor. Equivalently, this might be about PKR 3,000+ per hour for heavy tillage, given a good tractor can till approximately an acre in an hour. On easier light-work (like running a shallow tiller), the rate could be a bit lower or negotiated as a lump sum for the field.
- Harvesting (combine harvesters): Commonly priced per acre for grain crops like wheat and rice. A combine harvester service in Punjab/Sindh may charge around PKR 5,000–7,000 per acre ($18–$25) for wheat harvesting including cutting, threshing, and grain cleaning into bags. If a threshing crew is separate (e.g. using a stationary thresher for wheat or sunflower), they might charge per 40kg bag of grain threshed (for instance, PKR 50–70 per maund of wheat, which is ~PKR 1250–1750 per acre, though combines are more prevalent now). For crops like rice, some contractors take payment in kind (a portion of paddy as payment) especially if farmers are cash-strapped at harvest – an informal sharecropping-like arrangement. Large harvesting contractors sometimes differentiate prices based on crop yield or height (lodged crop that’s fallen over is harder to harvest, so they may quote higher).
- Threshing and Post-harvest: Where combines aren’t used, services like wheat threshing (after manual reaping) or maize shelling are charged per hour or per quantity. For example, a mobile thresher might cost PKR 2,000 per hour or PKR 200 per 100kg of wheat threshed – farmers choose whichever comes out cheaper. Similarly, corn cob shellers might charge by the bag.
- Laser land leveling: Typically per acre. Laser leveling – which greatly improves water efficiency – might be offered at PKR 2,000–3,000 per acre ($7–$11) in Punjab. Providers usually mount laser equipment on a tractor-drawn leveller and can level an acre in an hour or two depending on terrain. In some cases, the government has provided subsidies or vouchers for laser leveling services, but privately the rates fluctuate with diesel prices.
- Transport services: When farmers hire a tractor-trolley or a small truck for transport (e.g. carrying sugarcane to the mill or grain to market), it’s often a per trip or per distance charge. For instance, hauling produce from farm to the nearest market town (say 10 km) might cost PKR 3,000 per trip if using a tractor and large trolley, or more if longer distance. Some quote PKR per hour for transport if multiple short loads are involved. If the transport is for harvest (e.g. a tractor with trailer following the combine to collect grain), the fee might be integrated into the combine’s charges or paid separately per day.
-
Key factors influence these prices:
Fuel costs: Diesel is a major cost component. As fuel prices rise (currently ~PKR 260 per liter (ARY News, 2025)), service providers adjust rental rates upward. Many deals specify that the farmer will provide diesel for the tractor, with the service fee covering only the machine and operator. For example, a smallholder might supply 20 liters of diesel for ploughing his field, plus pay the operator’s fee. In other cases, the provider includes fuel in the price – then they are quick to revise rates if petrol/diesel gets more expensive. Volatility in fuel cost can lead to contentious price hikes right at peak season, which farmers often reluctantly accept due to lack of alternatives. - Machine type and horsepower: Newer or higher-capacity machines command higher fees. A powerful 85 HP tractor with a wide plough can cover more area per hour than a 50 HP tractor; providers may charge a premium for the bigger tractor but farmers might still prefer it as it finishes the job faster. Similarly, a modern, efficient combine harvester (like a newer Kubota or John Deere) may charge more per acre than an older Soviet-era combine, since it’s expected to do cleaner harvesting with less grain loss. That said, an aging machine might have higher downtime, so some farmers willingly pay extra for reliability. The age and condition of equipment thus indirectly affect pricing – well-maintained machines get a reputation (and perhaps a slight price premium) for not breaking down mid-job.
- Seasonal timing (peak vs off-peak): During peak demand periods, prices tend to spike due to scarcity of machines relative to farms needing service. In Punjab’s wheat belt, as the harvest begins (late March through April), combine harvester owners are in extreme demand – if there are more fields than combines, some owners will raise their rates or prioritize higher-paying clients. Smallholders sometimes complain of price gouging in such times. For example, what was PKR 4,000/acre last year might jump to PKR 5,500/acre this season if fuel rose and combines are few. Conversely, in off-season or slack periods, providers may offer discounts to keep their machine in use (or at least to maintain client relations). An entrepreneurial tractor owner might plough fallow fields in summer at a lower rate, or run a promotional price for laser leveling in the winter off-season, just to generate income when demand is low. Timing also impacts availability – farmers often book in advance for critical operations (some even “reserve” a tractor days ahead of sowing).
- Geographical accessibility: In well-connected villages with many service providers, competition can keep prices somewhat moderated. Farmers can shop around between 2–3 tractor owners in the vicinity. But in remote areas or tail-end villages, a single provider might have a monopoly and can charge higher. If a village is far from town, providers factor in travel time and fuel to get there. For instance, if a tractor has to drive 10 km to reach the client’s farm, the owner might add a flat charge for transportation or quote a slightly higher per acre rate to cover the commute. Areas with poor road access may simply have fewer machines available (because heavy equipment is hard to bring in), leading to localized higher rental costs.
- Trust and relationships: The informal nature of this market means personal relationships play a big role in pricing and payment. Regular customers – farmers who hire the same provider every season – might get preference and a modest “loyalty” discount or more lenient credit terms. New or unknown farmers might be quoted a bit higher until trust is built. There is often an element of patron-client relationship; for example, a small farmer may be a long-time sharecropper or neighbor to the tractor owner’s family, and thus the owner might charge him below-market rates as a goodwill gesture (or conversely, an exploitative landlord might bundle equipment hire with land rent at whatever rate he dictates). Bargaining is common – farmers will negotiate, perhaps citing a neighbor who paid less, and providers will justify their price citing diesel or some recent part replacement. In many cases, an agreed price is a package deal that includes some give-and-take in services (like “I’ll also pull your water pump out of the well with my tractor while I’m here, no extra charge”).
Another prevalent practice is the use of informal credit and deferred payment. Many smallholders cannot pay cash at the time of service (e.g. at planting, when they have yet to sell a crop). It’s common for rental service agreements to allow post-harvest payment. A tractor owner might plough a farmer’s land in October on the understanding that he will be paid in April after wheat harvest and sale. This is essentially an interest-free short-term loan embedded in the service. It relies on trust – the provider must trust that the farmer will honor the debt after harvest (and not default). Often these arrangements are reinforced by community ties or guarantors (e.g. the farmer’s landlord or a cousin might vouch for him). Such credit-based service is invaluable for cash-strapped farmers, but it can also influence pricing: providers might charge a bit more if accepting delayed payment to compensate for the risk. In some cases, instead of cash the payment might be in kind (a portion of crop yield). For example, a harvester owner could agree to take 1 maund (~40 kg) of wheat per acre as payment, which he then sells later – aligning his payment with the farmer’s harvest.
Overall, the market structure is informal, decentralized, and relationship-driven. There are no fixed tariffs; everything is by mutual agreement, albeit within prevailing price ranges known in the area. While this flexibility allows tailoring to each situation, it also means prices can vary widely even within the same district. Government agricultural extension or research departments sometimes publish guideline rates (and farmers’ forums share going rates), but enforcement is nonexistent in the informal sector. It truly is a localized market in each tehsil or village cluster, shaped by how many machines are around, who owns them, and the supply-demand balance at crunch time.
4. Barriers to Entry for New Providers
Despite the lucrative demand for machinery services, there are significant barriers to entry for anyone looking to become a new service provider in this market:
- High Capital Costs: Purchasing farm machinery requires a large upfront investment that is out of reach for many rural people. A basic new tractor (50–60 HP range) now costs on the order of PKR 2.5–3.0 million (≈$9,000–$11,000) (Tractors.com.pk, 2025), while a modern combine harvester can run PKR 8–12 million ($28–$43,000) or more. Even used machines have become expensive due to inflation. These sums are prohibitive in villages where incomes are modest. Prospective providers often lack the lump sum and need financing – but qualifying for large loans is itself a barrier (discussed below). Unlike some other small businesses, one cannot start a machinery rental service with just a few hundred dollars; the cost of entry is in the thousands of dollars at minimum. Additionally, implements like laser levelers, seed drills, or threshers add to the capital needed. The result is that only those with considerable resources (or strong financial backing) can enter the market as owners. Small farmers who might make excellent service providers (because they know local needs) are often unable to buy equipment due to these steep costs.
- Limited Access to Credit: Given the high capital need, financing is crucial – but rural credit access in Pakistan is notoriously difficult for the little guy. Banks typically require collateral (like land title) and have lengthy procedures. Many small farmers or aspiring entrepreneurs either don’t have sufficient collateral or find the process daunting. While specialized programs exist (e.g. the government’s tractor leasing schemes through ZTBL or Punjab’s interest-free loans up to PKR 50 million for machinery service providers (Business Recorder, 2025), these can be hard to tap into for a newcomer without connections. Even when loans are available, interest payments raise the effective cost. For example, if one takes a PKR 2 million loan to buy a tractor, servicing that debt means the rental income must not only cover operating costs but also monthly installments – a challenge in bad crop years. Microfinance institutions mostly focus on livestock or very small loans, not the scale needed for tractors. The upshot is financial barriers keep many out. Those who do manage to secure credit often do so via informal means: borrowing from relatives, pooling funds in a community, or getting an advance from a larger landowner to purchase equipment (essentially tying them into serving that landlord first). Lack of easy finance also means providers can’t easily expand – e.g. a mechanic who bought one tractor can’t get another quickly without significant savings. This throttles the supply of new providers entering the market.
- Operational and Maintenance Costs: Owning farm machinery isn’t a one-time expense – the ongoing operational costs are substantial and can deter entrants. Fuel alone can consume a big share of revenue, especially with volatile diesel prices. Maintenance is another heavy cost: tractors require regular servicing (engine oil, filters, hydraulics), and parts like tires or belts wear out. If a major breakdown occurs – say an engine overhaul or transmission failure – it can cost tens of thousands of PKR and sideline the machine for weeks. New entrants must be prepared for these costs or risk going bust. Experienced providers often are mechanics or hire mechanics to keep machines running; a newbie without technical skills might struggle. Moreover, operating in dusty, harsh farm conditions leads to frequent repairs – any aspirant provider needs to budget for ~10-15% of the machine cost annually in maintenance. Depreciation is also a factor: equipment loses value over time and with use, so a provider must earn enough to eventually replace old machinery. All these ongoing costs mean that someone who just barely managed to buy a tractor might find themselves unable to sustain the business if they didn’t anticipate the recurring expenses. It’s a barrier because it requires not only money but also know-how to maintain equipment efficiently. This is why many hesitate to enter unless they have mechanical experience or a partner who does.
- Need for Technical Know-How: Providing machinery services isn’t just about owning the machine – one must be able to operate it skillfully and safely, and adapt to different farm conditions. A prospective provider who doesn’t already know how to plow properly, calibrate a seed drill, or adjust a combine harvester for differing crop moisture, will face steep learning curves. Mistakes can be costly (e.g. improper combine settings can waste grain or even cause a fire in dry fields, and a poorly operated tractor can compact soil or damage the crop). So, lack of technical training is a barrier. While basic tractor driving might be common knowledge in rural areas, expertise in optimal operation and minor repairs is not universal. There are limited formal training avenues – agricultural vocational training is scarce (only a handful of polytechnics cover farm machinery, and extension services focus more on agronomy than machinery operation). New providers often learn by apprenticing: a young man might work as a tractor driver for someone else for a few seasons to pick up skills, before attempting to get his own tractor. Those who jump in without sufficient experience risk providing poor service (which hurts their reputation) or damaging their costly equipment. Thus, the need for a skilled operator – either oneself or a hired driver – is essential. Hiring an experienced operator is an added cost and can be hard to find during peak season when every tractor owner is also hiring drivers. In sum, technical barriers mean the field tends to be dominated by those who grew up around machinery or have hands-on experience, making it harder for an outsider to break in.
- Building a Client Base and Trust: Even if one overcomes the initial hurdles of buying a machine and knowing how to run it, a new provider faces the challenge of establishing a clientele in a market built on relationships. Farmers typically stick with service providers they know and trust, especially for time-critical tasks. A newcomer in the area might find farmers hesitant to switch to his services. It takes time to network, demonstrate reliability, and earn word-of-mouth referrals. During that time, the new provider might underutilize his machine (and idle machinery is lost money). Additionally, penetrating a market where an incumbent (say, the village landlord) already provides tractor hire can be politically sensitive – social hierarchies might make farmers shy to “defect” to a new provider. The informal nature means there’s no formal marketplace to advertise services; one has to literally go farm to farm or rely on local contacts. Trust is crucial because of the credit aspect – farmers will only take services on credit from someone they trust to be fair, and providers will only extend credit to farmers they trust to repay. A new provider has to either demand cash (which can limit clients) or take risks in extending credit to strangers. All this makes building a stable client base a gradual process. Many nascent providers struggle in the first couple of seasons and some give up if they can’t secure enough business to cover costs. Essentially, informational barriers and lack of networks make entry tough – it’s not a transparent, open market where one can easily grab market share with a better price. Reputation, often built over years, is the currency. New entrants must usually start by partnering or sub-contracting: for example, a new tractor owner might first work under an established contractor during harvest to get connected to farmers, before branching out solo. Without overcoming the trust barrier, a new provider with a shiny tractor could still fail to find customers in a tight-knit farming community.
These barriers mean that, despite high demand for machinery services, the supply side is constrained mostly to those with capital, know-how, and local clout. It explains why in provinces outside Punjab (e.g. Khyber Pakhtunkhwa or Balochistan), where fewer people meet those criteria, the service provider ecosystem is weaker. The government acknowledges these hurdles – for instance, Punjab’s recent program aims to give interest-free loans up to PKR 50 million (≈$178,500) to encourage new service enterprises and group ownership of machinery (Business Recorder, 2025). Easing access to finance and training could gradually lower the entry barriers. But as of now, becoming a machinery rental provider in rural Pakistan remains a venture requiring significant financial risk and technical competency, which many smallholders cannot take on easily.
5. Impact on Smallholders
The rise of informal machinery rental services has had profound impacts on smallholder farmers, both positive and negative. Access to affordable mechanization is often cited as a game-changer for small farms, but there are also challenges and limitations. Below we explore the benefits to smallholders, the associated challenges, and even do a brief cost-benefit look by crop where data allows.
Benefits for Small Farmers:
- Access to Modern Technology: Perhaps the biggest benefit is that smallholders who could never afford a tractor or harvester outright can still use one when needed. Renting democratizes access to equipment. A farmer with 5 acres can hire a laser land leveler for a day and achieve precision leveling that improves his irrigation efficiency, something only big farms with expensive gear could do before. Similarly, hiring a combine harvester allows even subsistence farmers to utilize a machine that costs crores of rupees. “Renting facilities will be a breath of fresh air for farmers, allowing them to use the latest technology without financial constraints,” as one farmer, Asim Ali, put it (Saleem, 2025). This exposure to modern tech can boost yields – for example, a smallholder using a tractor-mounted seed drill will get more uniform plant stands than broadcasting seed by hand, potentially raising output.
- Timeliness of Operations: For many crops, timing is everything. Rental services enable timely land preparation and harvesting, which has direct yield impacts. For instance, in wheat, each day of delay in planting past the optimal date can cut yields by roughly 1-2%. By hiring tractors, smallholders can prepare their fields quickly after the previous harvest and plant on time. Likewise, at harvest, hiring a combine means the crop can be gathered at the optimal moment (avoiding shattering losses or storms). Without machines, a small farmer might take weeks to harvest manually what a combine can do in hours – during which grain could be lost to birds, weather or over-ripening. Studies have linked mechanization to higher cropping intensity; in Punjab and Sindh, farmers using tractor services are often able to sow a second crop immediately after the first harvest, effectively doubling their annual cropping on the same land (Saroj, 2015). This is a huge boost to incomes. Timely tractor plowing also helps with pest and weed control (by quickly turning the soil). In short, rental services save time in critical periods, and time saved is yield gained. Labor Cost Savings: Mechanization through rentals can reduce the need (and cost) for manual labor on small farms. Hiring human labor for tasks like land preparation or threshing is both slow and increasingly expensive as rural wages rise. For example, manually harvesting and threshing an acre of wheat might require several laborers over multiple days, costing perhaps PKR 3,000+ in wages (plus meals), similar to what a combine would charge – but the combine finishes in an hour with less grain loss. Often, the machine service ends up cheaper or equal to the labor cost, with far less hassle. This is especially true when labor is scarce. In peak seasons, finding enough laborers can be difficult; by renting equipment, smallholders aren’t at the mercy of labor shortages. In crops like rice, where timely transplanting is crucial, some farmers now hire mechanical transplanters or direct drill seeders through service providers, which, while not yet very widespread, save on the huge labor of transplanting by hand. Overall, rentals allow small farms to substitute costly labor with efficient capital – improving their cost structure.
- Quality and Yield Improvements: Many mechanized operations not only save time but also improve agronomic quality. Laser land leveling (often done by rental service in Punjab) can improve water distribution and increase yields by 10-15% for irrigated crops, as research in Pakistan has shown. Similarly, using a mechanical thresher or combine can result in higher grain recovery than traditional manual threshing where more grain is lost. Even plowing deeply with a tractor (versus shallow plowing by oxen) can break hardpan and improve root growth, indirectly boosting yields. There’s evidence that widespread tractor use contributed to yield increases in the Green Revolution era. For smallholders today, the yield gap between those who use timely mechanized services and those who don’t can be significant. For example, in one region the wheat yield for farmers hiring tractors early for land prep averaged higher than those who prepared land late due to waiting for a neighbor’s bullocks. Mechanization also enables improved practices like precise row planting, better weed control (through machine hoeing or spraying using tractor-mounted sprayers), and reduced post-harvest losses by speedy processing. All these factors mean higher net output for the small farmer.
- Incremental Income and Diversification: With machines doing heavy work, farm families can redirect their labor to other productive activities. A smallholder who no longer needs to spend 10 days harvesting by hand might use that time to cultivate an additional leased parcel or do a side business. Renting machinery also allows diversification into new crops that would be impractical without mechanization. For instance, some small farmers could not grow maize or sugarcane (which require intensive harvesting) but now do so because they plan to hire a harvester or mechanized cutter. In areas where fodder choppers and silage packing machines are rented out (a new trend for dairy feed entrepreneurs (Mandapati, 2021), farmers can mechanize fodder preservation, freeing up time to perhaps keep more animals or grow an extra fodder crop. Essentially, access to machinery services can enhance a small farm’s overall productivity and income potential, contributing to rural livelihoods.
Challenges and Downsides for Smallholders:
- Rental Costs and Profit Margins: While renting is cheaper than owning, it is still a significant cash outlay that eats into a smallholder’s profit. If crop prices are low, the cost of hiring machinery can make profitability slim. For example, a tenant farmer growing wheat on 2 acres might spend PKR 10,000 (≈$36) on tractor services (plowing, drilling, harvesting). If his gross income from those 2 acres is, say, PKR 100,000, then 10% of his revenue went just to machinery rental. Add other costs (seeds, fertilizer, rent) and his net margin might be quite low. In bad years, some farmers feel burdened by machinery fees, especially if they had to take those services on credit – the debt at harvest time reduces their take-home earnings. There is also the risk of “price gouging” in peak season as noted: smallholders sometimes have no choice but to pay high rates when demand exceeds supply, which can further squeeze their margins. Unlike large farmers who might absorb costs over many acres, a small farmer’s bottom line is very sensitive to these expenses. So, while yields improve, the net profit might not improve as much if rental costs are high. This is a delicate balance: the technology must increase yield or reduce other costs enough to justify its hire expense. In many cases it does, but farmers remain wary of too-high charges.
- Dependence and Availability Issues: Smallholders are highly dependent on service availability. If the provider is late or machines are all booked, the small farmer is left waiting, potentially missing critical timing. This dependence means vulnerability – e.g. if a combine breaks down or doesn’t show up, the farmer’s crop could spoil. In peak periods, many small farmers report difficulty securing a tractor exactly when needed; they may end up in a queue behind larger clients. Unfortunately, providers often prioritize bigger plots first (since it’s more lucrative to finish a 10-acre job than ten 1-acre jobs). So the smallest farms might get serviced last, causing delays. There’s also the phenomenon of regional shortages – for instance, if unseasonal rains narrow the harvest window, everyone calls the combine owners at once, and there just aren’t enough machines to cover all fields in time. This availability risk weighs on small farmers, who sometimes resort to suboptimal manual methods if a machine isn’t accessible. Essentially, reliance on external service introduces uncertainty – the farmer is not fully in control of timing.
- Quality of Service (Machine/Operator): Not all service providers are equal. Smallholders often have to accept whatever machine comes, and sometimes they are old or poorly maintained. An unreliable tractor might break down mid-field, causing delay. A combine in bad condition might spill grain or mix too much straw, reducing the farmer’s yield quality. Furthermore, the skill of the operator matters. A careless tractor driver could damage field levies or leave patches un-ploughed; a combine operator without finesse might leave grain unharvested at the edges. There have been complaints, for example, of untrained operators causing grain losses up to 15% with outdated harvesters and methods (Dawn, 2022) – a significant hit to a farmer’s production. Smallholders have little recourse if service quality is poor; the transaction is informal, and they usually still have to pay the agreed fee. Some might avoid a particular provider next time, but in areas with few options, they may have to endure sub-par quality. Also, safety issues arise – e.g. a malfunctioning wheat thresher can be dangerous, and small farmers have suffered accidents when hiring such equipment, though this is more a concern for laborers operating them. Overall, variability in machine performance and operator skill can sometimes negate part of the benefit of mechanization for small farmers.
- Peak Season Price Hikes and Exploitation: As discussed, smallholders are at risk of being overcharged in high-demand times or under informal exploitative arrangements. For instance, a large landlord who rents out his tractor to his tenant might bundle it with conditions (like forcing the tenant to also buy inputs from him or sell crop to him at low price). These power dynamics can exploit the dependent position of the small farmer. In some cases, providers collude locally to set a going rate, leaving farmers no bargaining power. If a smallholder is cash-poor and must ask for service on credit, he might be charged a premium or have to agree to give a larger crop share. Such practices mean the benefits of mechanization can be uneven – the poorest farmers might actually pay the highest per-unit costs due to their weak position. Additionally, if government-subsidized services (like a state-run tractor pool) are mismanaged or captured by local elites, smallholders may not actually get the intended low rates and instead must go to the same informal market.
- Inappropriate Sizing and Over-Mechanization: Sometimes small plots are not ideally suited to large machines. A combine harvester might have difficulty in a tiny irregular one-acre patch, leading to crop damage on field edges. Similarly, heavy tractors on very small plots can cause soil compaction if not managed well. There are cases where farmers hired a big 85HP tractor which turned out to be overkill – it plowed too deep or too roughly on a fragile soil, affecting the next crop. In essence, smallholders have limited choice of equipment tailor-made for small farms (like two-wheel mini tractors or small combines) because the market is dominated by medium-sized machines servicing everyone. Pakistan has not widely adopted the small-scale mechanization seen in countries like China (two-wheel walking tractors, mini-combines) on a large scale; thus smallholders get by with what’s available, even if not optimal for their scale. This can lead to less-than-ideal outcomes in some scenarios (e.g. high fuel use on tiny plots, or inability of large combine to navigate a small terraced field). However, this challenge is gradually being addressed as companies introduce smaller machinery and service providers diversify offerings.
Cost-Benefit Examples: To illustrate the impact, consider a cost-benefit example for wheat in Punjab for a small farmer versus traditional methods:
- Without mechanization: Farmer would hire labor to manually harvest and thresh wheat. Suppose harvesting an acre by hand costs PKR 2,500 in labor and takes several days, and threshing with oxen or basic thresher costs another PKR 1,000, with grain losses of ~5% due to handling. Total cost ~PKR 3,500 and yield loss.
- With rented combine: Farmer pays maybe PKR 5,000 for a combine per acre (modern rates), but the combine does it in an hour with grain loss ~1-2%. Labor cost is near zero for harvesting. Although the cash outlay is higher, the farmer saves time (can immediately plant another crop or sell grain earlier) and gets a bit more yield due to less loss. If wheat yield is 40 maunds/acre (~1600 kg) and price PKR 1500 per maund, a 3-4% extra grain saved is roughly PKR 1,800-2,400 more income, which actually offsets a large part of the combine fee. So the net benefit might be positive when considering both cost and output. Moreover, the farmer avoids the hassle of managing labor for days.
- For rice in Sindh, using a rented transplanter might cost PKR 2,000/acre, but can improve plant spacing and yield, and allows 2 acres/day to be planted vs 0.25 acre/day by hand. This means the farmer can cultivate a larger area or ensure all his area is planted in the optimal window, leading to higher overall production that often justifies the extra cost.
- Sugarcane: a small farmer might not afford a mechanical cutter or loader, but if he hires one via a contractor, it might reduce the harvesting time from weeks to days, reducing weight loss (sugarcane loses sugar content if it’s not promptly delivered to the mill). The increased sugar recovery could pay for the machine hire.
Each situation varies, but numerous studies in South Asia show that mechanization services tend to have a positive cost-benefit for smallholders in terms of labor saved and yield gained, provided the rental price isn’t exorbitant (Saroj, 2015). The Government and researchers often cite examples of yield and income improvements where custom hire services are available to small farmers. In Bangladesh, for instance, nearly all small farms hire power tillers and have seen cropping intensity rise and labor drudgery fall as a result – a pattern that Pakistan’s smallholders are also experiencing as they increasingly rely on rented machines.
In summary, the impact on smallholders is largely beneficial: they get to partake in the fruits of mechanization – increased productivity, timely farming, and often better incomes – without heavy capital investment. However, these benefits can be undermined by high service costs, availability issues, or subpar service quality. Supporting and regulating the informal rental market (without stifling it) could enhance the net positive impact, ensuring small farmers reliably get the services they need at fair prices.
6. Digital Tools and “Uber for Tractors”
With the digital revolution, one might expect that even agriculture in Pakistan could leverage mobile platforms to match farmers needing services with machinery owners – essentially an “Uber for tractors” model. Are such apps or platforms in use in Pakistan? The concept exists, but uptake remains nascent and experimental so far. Traditional face-to-face networks still dominate, yet several digital initiatives are worth noting:
- Hello Tractor and Global Models: Globally, services like Hello Tractor (pioneered in Africa) have drawn attention as the “Uber of Tractors,” using a mobile app and IoT devices to connect tractor owners with farmers who need field work (Splitter, 2019; Kloberdanz, 2020). Hello Tractor’s model relies on a smartphone app for booking and GPS tracking of tractors. While Hello Tractor started in Nigeria, by the late 2010s it expanded to Asia and reportedly had a presence (or at least pilot programs) in countries like Pakistan and Bangladesh (Gitari, 2022). For example, Hello Tractor has been piloted in Pakistan via partnerships, allowing farmers to send a request through an app or SMS, which is then routed to nearby tractor owners (often via a local agent who aggregates farmer requests) (Grow Further, 2022). However, these pilots have been limited in scale. The typical outcome so far is that most farmers still rely on a human middleman (booking agent) to use such a system, rather than directly using the app (Daum et al., 2021). So, while the technology exists, the on-ground usage in Pakistan at the farmer level has been low. One reason is that smartphone penetration and digital literacy among older farmers is limited – many smallholders either don’t have internet-enabled phones or are not comfortable with apps.
- Local Pakistani Apps and Platforms: The government and startups have made some attempts. In 2019, the Government of Pakistan showed interest in replicating India’s model by announcing the development of a platform similar to India’s CHC (Custom Hiring Centers) Farm Machinery app (AutoTrader Commercial, 2020). Punjab’s Agriculture Department, under its reforms, has been exploring digital directories of service providers. For instance, there were reports of a provincial app being developed where registered service providers (the 20,000+ in Punjab) could be listed for farmers to contact. As of 2025, this is still in progress and not yet widely deployed. On the startup side, a few agri-tech entrepreneurs have launched initiatives: apps that let you book tractors or other implements. One example is a startup in Lahore that created an Uber-like interface for booking tractor trolley services for crop transport. Another is a service where farmers send an SMS to a short code to request a laser land leveler, and the system matches them to an available operator in the district. These services remain in early stages and face the challenge of scaling up a two-sided marketplace (enough farmers and enough providers using the app). Digital agri-hubs like BaKhabar Kissan (a mobile platform for farmers) have also mulled integrating rental listings, but currently they focus more on information dissemination (BKK, n.d.).
- Experiences from India and Bangladesh: Comparing with neighbors, India has made a push in digital solutions for farm rentals. The Indian government launched the multi-lingual CHC Farm Machinery app in 2019 (AutoTrader Commercial, 2020), aiming to let farmers hire tractors, rotavators, harvesters, etc., from custom hiring centers or individual owners nearby. Private sector in India also saw companies like Trringo (by Mahindra) and EM3 Agri Services (Samadhan) acting as Uber-like intermediaries – farmers call a hotline or use an app, and the company dispatches a tractor from its hubs (Daum et al., 2021; Kloberdanz, 2020). These initiatives have met mixed success. Trringo eventually scaled back operations, and EM3 found that a heavy on-ground presence (with field coordinators) was needed to actually connect farmers and machines – pure app-based matchmaking wasn’t enough because of trust and tech barriers. Bangladesh, with its very small farm sizes, has also experimented with digital matchmaking. A notable example is the private company ACI in Bangladesh conceptualizing an Uber-like app to connect scattered small farms with available machinery, given their average farm size is only ~1.3 acres (Ansarey, n.d.). The idea is to aggregate demand so that machinery owners can serve multiple tiny plots efficiently. They envisioned features like real-time availability, transparent pricing, and even remote tracking of work done via telematics (Ansarey, n.d.). As of now, Bangladesh’s mechanization is still largely coordinated by informal brokers rather than a nationwide app, but digital solutions are slowly emerging (e.g., some Uber-style services for power tillers in the north, often run by development projects linking farmers to machine owners via SMS).
-
Adoption Challenges: Why hasn’t “Uber for tractors” taken off widely in Pakistan yet? Several challenges:
- Digital Literacy & Access: Many small farmers either don’t use smartphones or apps, or if they do (often via a younger family member), they may not be aware of or trust an agri-specific app. The average age of principal farmers is high, and although smartphone use is rising, there is a learning curve. In rural Pakistan, voice calls and WhatsApp are more commonly used than specialized apps.
- Trust and Relationships: Farmers currently rely on people they know. Convincing them to request a random tractor via app, operated by someone they’ve never met, is difficult. Trust is crucial given the credit aspect – an app can’t easily guarantee that the service provider will allow pay-after-harvest, for instance. Nor can it guarantee quality of work, which personal reputation currently vouches for. So farmers stick to trusted local providers and use phones simply to call and schedule, rather than a new platform.
- Logistical Coordination: Unlike urban ride-sharing where the “product” is just a ride, farm services are more complex. A tractor service might need assessment of the task (type of implement, soil condition) before quoting a price. There’s also the issue of locating a farm – pinning a precise location in a village and navigating a tractor there is not as straightforward as a car to a street address. Apps have to incorporate maps of rural areas which may be incomplete.
- Scale and Network Effect: For a digital platform to work, it needs a critical mass of service providers and farmers on it. In early stages, farmers may check an app and find no tractors available in their area (because providers haven’t signed up), which discourages usage, and vice versa. Building that network effect likely requires heavy promotion and possibly incentives for early adopters.
- Payment Systems: Many existing apps globally expect digital payments or at least formal transactions. In Pakistan’s context, cash on delivery (or post-service) is the norm and needs to be accommodated. There’s also the matter of possibly handling partial payments or disputes, which apps aren’t yet equipped to mediate in real-time (e.g., what if a farmer claims the work wasn’t done properly? On Uber you can rate your driver, but on a farm app, a bad rating doesn’t solve the lost yield).
- Language and Interface: Apps must be in local languages (Punjabi, Sindhi, etc.) with user-friendly interfaces for farmers. Some efforts have done this, but it’s an ongoing process to make technology truly accessible to a largely oral culture of communication.
Despite these challenges, digital tools are gradually making inroads. We see hybrid models emerging: call centers or WhatsApp groups run by organizations to connect farmers to machinery. For example, a district agriculture office might run a WhatsApp group where service providers announce availability and farmers post requests – a semi-digital marketplace. Social media is also playing a role; Facebook groups where tractors or combines are advertised for hire are popping up in Pakistan, effectively informal digital classifieds.
Looking ahead, as younger, more tech-savvy individuals take up farming, the adoption of apps could improve. The concept of an “Uber for tractors” is attractive because it promises to reduce the transaction costs of finding a machine (Daum et al., 2020). Instead of walking village to village to see who can come plow, a farmer could press a button. Additionally, such platforms could increase competition and transparency in pricing – a farmer could see quotes from multiple providers. For providers, digital platforms might help in scheduling and maximizing utilization (less idle time).
One real example within Pakistan’s neighborhood is the success of custom hire apps in India’s Punjab for renting combine harvesters across states; similarly, Pakistan could benefit, for instance, by coordinating the movement of surplus combines from Punjab toSindh for the rice harvest via an app. There are reports that Pakistan Agricultural Machinery and Implements Manufacturers Association (PAMIMA) is considering an app to deploy machinery where needed in peak seasons, inspired by Uber-like logistics. In summary, digital tools for farm machinery rental in Pakistan are in their infancy. No app has yet become the go-to nationwide platform. The informal market remains largely analog – phone calls and local brokers. However, pilot initiatives by startups and government indicate a growing interest in leveraging smartphones to streamline custom hiring. As infrastructure (mobile broadband in villages) improves and trust in digital services grows, we may see increasing “uberization” of tractor hiring in the coming years. Until then, the human element remains key, with digital solutions complementing rather than fully replacing the traditional system.
7. Policy & Future Outlook
Policy makers in Pakistan recognize the importance of mechanization for smallholders and have begun to address the needs of the informal rental market indirectly through various programs. Looking ahead, a combination of supportive policies and emerging trends will shape the future of machinery rentals. Here we discuss current relevant policies and schemes, and explore future outlook including cooperatives, financing, training, and factors like farm consolidation and climate change.
Government Programs and Policies:
For decades, Pakistan’s government has promoted farm mechanization mainly via subsidy schemes for purchasing tractors and implements. Since the late 1960s, federal and provincial authorities launched programs offering 30–70% subsidies on tractors (FAO, 2024), as well as subsidized distribution of laser levelers and other equipment in recent years. Examples include the Punjab Green Tractor Scheme (various iterations, e.g. in 2008 and 2012) which provided youth farmers tractors at subsidized prices through a balloting process, and Sindh’s Benazir Tractor Scheme. These schemes directly helped a few thousand farmers purchase machines each time. While they weren’t aimed at rental services per se, many beneficiaries of tractor subsidies did become service providers, hiring out their new equipment to neighbors (as a way to repay the cost). In that sense, subsidies indirectly bolstered the custom hire market by seeding more privately-owned machines. However, critics note these programs often favored well-connected or larger farmers and did not always reach the smallest cultivators.
Recognizing the gap, the government (especially Punjab province) is now turning attention to supporting service providers and cooperative ownership models. The Punjab government’s new initiative under the Transforming Agriculture Program (part of the Green Pakistan Initiative) explicitly mentions launching agricultural machinery rental services at the tehsil level (Business Recorder, 2025). This involves setting up or encouraging Agri Service Centers where 25 types of modern machinery will be available on rent via private service providers, with government facilitation. To implement this, Punjab in 2025 has proposed interest-free financing (up to PKR 50 million) for those who invest in machinery to rent out (Business Recorder, 2025), and is negotiating with international donors (ADB) for loans to establish centers for machinery standards and testing (FAO, 2024). The idea is to replicate the success seen in Punjab’s dense network of providers to other provinces – the FAO notes Punjab’s model of over 20,000 service providers is a “success story” that could be copied in Sindh, KP, and Balochistan (FAO, 2024). Some provinces like Khyber Pakhtunkhwa (KP) have tried government-run Model Farm Service Centers at district level (Amjad, 2017) which, among other things, rent out machines or facilitate sharing, but the scale remains limited.
In policy dialogues (e.g. in 2024 under a FAO project), stakeholders emphasized the need for a national agricultural mechanization policy focusing on smallholders (FAO, 2024). They specifically recommended defining and strengthening the role of private service providers in reaching small farms (FAO, 2024). This might translate into formal recognition or support for those providers – possibly through registration, training, and maybe subsidized fuel or spare parts to lower their costs. So far, however, there is no separate law or policy regulating the custom hire market; it operates in the private domain.
Another policy tool is credit support. The State Bank of Pakistan has some refinance schemes for farm machinery and implements, and there was mention of a Credit Guarantee Scheme for small farmers to get loans for machinery (FAO, 2024). If effectively implemented, easier credit could allow more modest farmers to purchase machines (either individually or as a group) to use and rent out. The success of such credit programs will determine if new entrants can overcome the barriers discussed earlier.
Suggested Interventions & Cooperative Models:
Experts often suggest forming cooperatives or group-based ownership models so that small farmers can collectively own machinery. For instance, 8–10 farmers could jointly buy a tractor through a cooperative, each contributing and sharing its use (and renting it out to others when idle). This model has worked in some countries via co-ops or farmers’ associations. In Pakistan, co-operatives historically haven’t been very strong in agriculture (barring a few irrigation water user associations, etc.), but there’s renewed interest in custom hiring cooperatives. The government could incentivize this by providing grants or interest-free loans to registered farmer groups to purchase, say, a combine harvester that none of them could afford alone. Cooperative management can be tricky (to avoid conflicts in scheduling or maintenance responsibilities), so training in group governance would be needed. But if successful, it can empower smallholders to be both users and providers of machinery services, cutting out some of the dependency on private owners.
Another suggestion is rental financing and leasing innovations. Much like car leasing, companies could lease tractors or equipment to rural entrepreneurs with repayment tied to usage. Some private banks (e.g. Bank of Punjab’s Tractor Lease program (The Bank of Punjab, n.d.) have started doing this with conditions (like requiring a minimum land holding). Expanding such programs and making them accessible to service-oriented owners (not just farmers using on their own land) could bring more machines into the rental pool. Likewise, pay-as-you-go models are being tried – for example, Hello Tractor’s finance model assesses if an entrepreneur has booked sufficient hectares via the app, then helps finance a tractor which is paid off gradually by rental earnings (Hello Tractor, n.d.). Adapting this model in Pakistan (maybe through local fintech or telecom partnerships) could lower the entry cost for young service providers.
Vocational Training and Technical Support:
To address the human capital barrier, governments and NGOs are looking at boosting vocational training in farm machinery operation and repair. Punjab has some agricultural training institutes, but a new focus is short courses for tractor/combine operators and mechanics. If more youth are trained and certified, they can either become reliable operators (whom service providers can hire) or even start their own rental services with confidence in their skills. For instance, training programs by organisations like USAID or FAO in other countries have created a cadre of “custom hire service providers” by first teaching them business and technical skills, then linking them with credit to get machinery – a model that could be emulated. The National Vocational & Technical Training Commission (NAVTTC) could incorporate machinery operation modules, and manufacturers like Millat (Massey Ferguson) or Al-Ghazi (Fiat New Holland) could sponsor operator training as part of corporate social responsibility. Such efforts would professionalize the rental market over time, improving service quality for farmers.
Technical support in terms of maintenance services in rural areas is also key. One reason service providers cluster around towns is access to mechanics and spare parts. Expanding networks of maintenance workshops or mobile repair units deeper into rural areas (possibly via public-private partnership) would help keep machines running in far-flung places, encouraging more providers to serve those areas. Government could consider subsidizing the establishment of machinery workshops in underserved regions.
Digital Access and Information:
As discussed, improving digital access can grease the wheels of the rental market. Government extension could maintain a simple directory of service providers (perhaps on a website or via SMS query) so that farmers know whom to contact if they need, say, a rice thresher in their area. Even a toll-free helpline that provides info on available machinery rentals (analogous to crop advisory hotlines) could be beneficial. Over time, if the “Uber for tractors” concept takes firmer hold, the policy could be to integrate it with government efforts – for example, a government app listing registered providers who maybe meet certain standards or have set maximum rates. Caution is needed not to over-regulate an informal market which currently self-regulates; however, some soft intervention to increase transparency (like publishing typical rate ranges, or helping mediate disputes if any) could build trust.
Future Trends – Farm Consolidation:
One factor that will influence the machinery rental market is the structure of farms. Pakistan has seen fragmentation of landholdings over the past decades (average farm size halved from ~5.3 ha in 1970s to ~2.6 ha by 2010 (Wattoo & Mehmood, 2023), which actually increases the need for custom hiring since smaller farms can’t justify owning machines. If this fragmentation trend continues (due to inheritance and population pressure), the rental market could become even more important, with even more farms relying on even fewer machines. Conversely, if some consolidation happens (through land leasing or corporate farming initiatives), slightly larger farms (say 20-30 acres) might begin to purchase their own machinery, possibly reducing demand for outside services in some pockets. However, given that nearly 90% of farms are below 12.5 acres (Ali, 2023), any realistic consolidation in the near future will still leave a vast majority of smallholders in need of rental services. An interesting dynamic could be large agribusiness or contract farming operations that invest in machinery and provide services to their contracted small farmers (sort of an integrated model). For example, a sugar mill could run a fleet of harvesters to cut cane for its suppliers. If corporate actors step in, the market might see some formalization and potentially more predictability in service provision, though it might also sideline independent small providers.
Climate Change and Resilience:
Climate change is expected to impact agriculture in Pakistan with more erratic weather, floods, droughts, and shifting growing seasons. This has a few implications for the machinery rental sphere:
- With unpredictable weather, the timing of operations might become even more critical – e.g. suddenly a window of a few dry days is available to harvest before a rain spell. This will increase the reliance on fast mechanized operations. Demand for machinery services could grow and be more last-minute, stressing the current informal systems. Better coordination (possibly through digital means) will be needed to respond quickly to such short windows.
- Extreme events like floods (such as the 2022 devastating floods) can destroy farm equipment of those who owned it, and also create emergency demand for machinery (e.g. tractors to rehabilitate land, pumps to drain water). Smallholders who lost draft animals or equipment in floods will depend on rental services to recover. Policies might consider disaster relief in form of providing machinery services (for example, after floods, government contracting service providers to plough fields of affected small farmers for free or at subsidized rates). There’s precedence in providing seed/fertilizer after disasters; including mechanization in recovery plans could be vital.
- Climate change may also spur new types of machinery (like zero-tillage seeders for conservation agriculture to cope with erratic rainfall, or planters for climate-resilient crop varieties). These might initially be expensive or unfamiliar, so introducing them through custom hire services makes sense. Already, technologies like drones for pesticide spraying or solar-powered irrigation pumps are on the horizon. We can foresee service companies offering, say, drone spraying services to small farms (since buying a drone is not feasible for them). The FAO report hinted that service providers’ role will expand with the arrival of drones and solar tech (FAO, 2024). This means the informal rental market might diversify beyond tractors and combines to include high-tech services (e.g., a startup offering drone crop monitoring on a service basis).
- On the flip side, mechanization must adapt to ensure it’s climate-smart (e.g., not contributing excessively to emissions or soil degradation). Policies promoting conservation agriculture equipment in rental fleets can help smallholders adopt climate-resilient practices. For instance, encouraging service providers to offer zero-till drills after rice to sow wheat (to save moisture and reduce burning of crop residue) could both improve climate outcomes (less CO₂ from burning, better soil health) and keep service businesses busy in a new segment.
Conclusion & Outlook:
The informal farm machinery rental market in Pakistan has become an indispensable support system for millions of smallholder farmers. It emerged organically out of necessity – a creative solution wherein those with resources invest in machinery and provide services to those without. This has led to increased productivity and rural employment (as machine operators, etc.), and effectively created a new class of rural entrepreneurs. Going forward, if nurtured properly, this model can be a win-win: small farmers continue to get affordable access to mechanization, while service providers run profitable ventures that contribute to the rural economy.
To strengthen this sector, the future likely holds:
- More formal recognition and support – e.g., possibly associations of service providers, inclusion in agricultural policy planning, and extension services tailored to them.
- Technology infusion – both in terms of more advanced machinery (small-scale machines, precision ag tools) and digital management (platforms to link farmers and providers, GPS tracking, etc.).
- Increased competition and possibly lower costs for farmers – as the number of providers grows with government incentives, farmers may benefit from more competitive pricing and availability. Government rental stations (if any are set up at tehsil level) could also serve as price benchmarks, preventing excessive overcharging in private market by offering an alternative.
- Regional expansion – currently Punjab leads in service provision; we can expect provinces like Sindh and KP to catch up if targeted programs encourage machinery services there. For example, Sindh might particularly push combine harvester services in rice and wheat, since currently many combines there migrate from Punjab.
- Cooperative and cluster approaches – small farmers banding together to obtain services or assets. Already, in some areas farmers informally coordinate (e.g., 5 neighboring small farms will get ploughed in one go and collectively negotiate a price). Formalizing this into cooperative hiring could yield better bargains for them and assured business for providers.
- Sustainability concerns – Ensuring that the proliferation of machinery doesn't lead to issues like overuse of heavy tractors causing soil compaction or replacing too much labor and causing rural unemployment. Thus far, labor displaced by machines in Pakistan has generally found other employment (given overall labor shortages and migration), but policy should monitor this balance. The ideal is to use machines for what they do best (tedious, time-sensitive tasks), and free up human labor for higher-value tasks or non-farm opportunities.
In conclusion, the informal rental market in Pakistan has shown tremendous ingenuity and resilience in meeting smallholders' needs. With thoughtful support – credit facilitation, training, smart subsidies, and digital integration – it can be enhanced further. Small farmers stand to gain through improved yields, cropping intensity, and incomes, helping ensure national food security. As one stakeholder succinctly put it: empowering service providers and making mechanization accessible "benefits all farmers, including women and marginalized groups" (FAO, 2024) – it is a pathway to inclusive agricultural growth. The next decade will be critical in scaling up this model sustainably, bridging the mechanization gap for Pakistan's farmers while adapting to a changing economic and climatic landscape.
Note: All monetary figures are in PKR with USD in brackets at a rate of PKR 280 = $1.
References
- Ali, M. F. (2023). Agricultural land consolidation. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics. Retrieved from https://pide.org.pk/research/agricultural-land-consolidation/
- Business Recorder. (2025, March 6). 25 types of agri machinery will be available on rent: Minister. Retrieved from https://www.brecorder.com/news/40351494/25-types-of-agri-machinery-will-be-available-on-rent-minister
- FAO. (2024). Agricultural mechanization for smallholder farmers in Pakistan: Results of a multistakeholder policy dialogue – Policy brief. Rome. https://doi.org/10.4060/cd1865en
- Saleem, M. (2025, March 11). Modern machinery rental service to boost agri production, cut expenses. INP-WealthPk. Retrieved from https://www.inp.net.pk/article-detail/inp-wealthpk/modern-machinery-rental-service-to-boost-agri-production-cut-expenses
- Houssou, N., Asante-Addo, C., Diao, X., & Kolavalli, S. (2015). Big tractors, but small farms: Tractor hiring services as a farmer-owner’s response to an under-developed agricultural machinery market. IFPRI Ghana Strategy Support Program Working Paper 39. Retrieved from https://cgspace.cgiar.org/server/api/core/bitstreams/d77e05bc-aeff-46d7-8f46-dc2c5bce5df0/content
- Tractors.com.pk. (2025). New tractor prices in Pakistan 2025 – MF, NH, MTL, AGTL, IMT & Belarus. Retrieved from https://tractors.com.pk/new-tractor-prices-pakistan/
- ARY News. (2025, March 15). Govt announces petroleum prices for the next fortnight. ARY News. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://arynews.tv/petrol-price-in-pakistan-effective-march-15-2025/
- Saroj, S. (2015, September 16). Benefits of practicing custom hiring services of agricultural machinery. IFPRI South Asia. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://southasia.ifpri.info/2015/09/16/benefits-of-practicing-custom-hiring-services-of-agricultural-machinery/
- Mandapati, J. (2021, October 4). Machine hiring centers create jobs for youth while saving time, cost and labor for farmers. CGIAR Research Program on Water, Land and Ecosystems. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://archive.iwmi.org/wle/news/machine-hiring-centers-create-jobs-youth-while-saving-time-cost-and-labor-farmers/
- Dawn. (2022, January 7). Outdated wheat harvesting wastes 15pc of yield. Dawn. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://www.dawn.com/news/1668046
- Splitter, J. (2019, August 12). What the Uber of tractors means for the future of agtech in Africa. Forbes. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://www.forbes.com/sites/jennysplitter/2019/08/12/what-the-uber-of-tractors-means-for-the-future-of-agtech-in-africa/
- Grow Further. (2022, January 13). "Uber for Tractors" Gains Traction at Smallholder Farms. Grow Further. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://www.growfurther.org/uber-for-tractors-gains-traction-at-smallholder-farms/
- Daum, T., Villalba, R., Anidi, O., Mayienga, S. M., Gupta, S., & Birner, R. (2021). Uber for tractors? Opportunities and challenges of digital tools for tractor hire in India and Nigeria. World Development, 144, 105480. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2021.105480
- AutoTrader Commercial. (2020, March 10). Uber for tractors only the start. AutoTrader. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://www.autotrader.co.za/commercial/news-and-advice/agriculture-news/uber-for-tractors-only-the-start/6610
- BKK. (n.d.). Bakhabar Kissan [Mobile application software]. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://play.google.com/store/apps/details?id=com.switchsolutions.agricultureapplication.mobilink&hl=en_US&pli=1
- Ansarey, F. H. (n.d.). Agri-apps for agricultural equipment rental services. ACI Limited. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://www.aci-bd.com/research-development/agri-apps-for-agricultural-equipment-rental-services.html
- Daum, T., Villalba, R., Anidi, O., Mayienga, S. M., Gupta, S., & Birner, R. (2020). Uber for tractors? Opportunities and challenges of digital tools for tractor hire in India and Nigeria. Hohenheim Working Papers on Social and Institutional Change in Agricultural Development, (001-2020). Universität Hohenheim. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://research4agrinnovation.org/app/uploads/2020/01/Working_Papers_1_Uber-1.pdf
- Amjad, N. (2017, December). Strategizing mechanized agriculture in Pakistan. 5th Regional Forum on Sustainable Agricultural Mechanization in Asia and the Pacific. Pakistan Agricultural Research Council. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://un-csam.org/sites/default/files/2020-11/9.%20PPT_Pakistan.pdf
- The Bank of Punjab. (n.d.). BOP Tractor Lease. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://www.bop.com.pk/BOP%20Tractor%20Lease
- Hello Tractor. (n.d.). Tractor financing. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://hellotractor.com/tractor-financing/
- Wattoo, K. S., & Mehmood, S. (2023, January 9). The challenge of shrinking farm sizes. Dawn. Retrieved April 8, 2025, from https://www.dawn.com/news/1730732